Taxes

The economic harms of the gross receipts tax (GRT) were well understood by the early 20th century. Not only is the tax inequitable, but it is also inefficient and distortionary. That is why most states abandoned GRTs in the early 1900s, as states developed the capacity to administer less harmful taxes. Unfortunately, some policymakers in Massachusetts want to turn back the clock.

Today, only a handful of states levy any variation of the GRT. Those that still rely on them as a significant source of revenue (like Texas, Nevada, Ohio, and Washington) typically do so in lieu of one or more alternative taxes. None of these states imposes a corporate income tax, and Ohio repealed several other business taxes as well when it adopted its GRT.

Some Massachusetts policymakers, however, want to layer a GRT atop the state’s existing corporate income tax. If H.2855 becomes law, it would reduce the competitiveness of the Bay State and increase prices for consumers on already expensive goods and services. To make matters worse, Bay Staters would be asked to shoulder the added tax burden at a time when inflation is already eroding purchasing power at a rate not seen 1982.

The GRT has persisted into the 21st century thanks, in part, to its claim of a guaranteed revenue stream. But therein lies the inequity. The so-called guaranteed revenue stream occurs because GRTs are assessed regardless of a company’s ability to pay, whether it lost money or earned a profit in any given year. The result is an inequitable tax that forces struggling firms further into the red and disproportionately harms businesses with narrow profit margins.

Unlike other states that have enacted GRTs, Massachusetts’ proposal intends to layer a broad-based tax on services and goods at all stages of production while retaining every component of the present tax regime. When Ohio adopted its GRT, known as the Commercial Activity Tax (CAT), in 2005, policymakers did so while simultaneously repealing the state’s corporate income tax, capital stock tax, and business tangible property tax. H.2855 takes an all-of-the-above approach and applies the GRT to all receipts obtained from sales, services, property deals, interest, rent, royalties, and miscellaneous other fees, without repealing any existing taxes. A 0.25 percent tax rate may seem low, but in the world of GRTs, it is not: it is virtually identical to Ohio’s 0.26 percent rate, which is in lieu of other business taxes.

The GRT also lacks transparency, which violates a key tenant of sound tax policy. Although GRTs usually apply to all intermediate transactions during production, consumers are generally unaware that when they purchase a retail product they are paying tax on the price of the good and at least one (perhaps several other) iteration of the GRT. The GRT adds a deadweight cost to production which is compounded as firms build the tax into their sale price at each stage of production. The GRT is compounded a final time when a sales tax is applied at the point of sale. This phenomenon, known as tax pyramiding, harms both producers and consumers as it artificially increases the final price of a good. In cases where there are few substitutes for a good or service, producers will pass the entire cost of the tax on to consumers. And where there are substitutes, Massachusetts businesses are at a disadvantage, because their out-of-state peers won’t have the tax embedded at each layer of their production.

Massachusetts policymakers know the harms of tax pyramiding, which is why there are exemptions for many business inputs in the Commonwealth’s sales tax. The GRT would effectively override many of those exemptions.

GRTs are infamous for their tax pyramiding effects, but H.2855 is uniquely inefficient. The bill’s exemption threshold creates a disincentive for investment; its broad nexus provision encourages outmigration; and the added cost for the tax base threatens to increase prices for consumers in Massachusetts and elsewhere.

The proposed bill includes a $50 million receipt exemption that is ostensibly designed to target large companies. However, reality may not abide the intention. Unlike the CIT, which accounts for the cost of property, materials, labor, services, interest paid, and other annual losses, GRTs do not deduct the costs of doing business. In high-cost industries or ones with low profit margins, even moderately sized firms by net income metrics could be subject to GRT liability.

Additionally, the exemption threshold creates an impediment for additional investment. Firms in low-margin industries would have little incentive to collect more than $50 million of receipts if additional investment would incur tax liability that negates meaningful return on investment.

Another source of inefficiency is attributable to H.2855’s broad nexus provisions. Under this proposal nexus is triggered, predictably, by a firm that conducts the preponderance of its business operations in the Commonwealth. However, nexus can also be achieved by economic activity as modest as a single employee living in Massachusetts but working remotely for an out-of-state firm. Under this nominal nexus threshold, H.2855 could tax the gross income of, say, a Texas-based firm whose sole activity in the Commonwealth involves a human resources contractor working remotely from her kitchen table in Springfield.

Particularly broad nexus provisions incentivize companies to prohibit employees from working remotely in jurisdictions where new tax liabilities could be incurred. The collective loss of remote workers’ income, sale, and property tax revenues due to outmigration or outright avoidance of the Commonwealth could well offset any new GRT revenue collected from out-of-state firms. In an age when remote work is rapidly becoming the norm, Massachusetts policymakers should set conditions to draw new workers to the state, not risk pushing them away.

Since there are relatively few substitutes for many of products subject to the proposed tax, the GRT on those goods will likely be passed entirely to consumers. But with the 12-month inflation rate at its highest point since 1982 and total spending on health care projected to reach 19 percent of GDP by 2025, Bay Staters do not need additional price increases. Yet the new GRT could provide just that by increasing the cost of everything from automobiles to lab equipment.

The GRT will apply to Massachusetts companies that produce common vehicle inputs such as sunroofs, cupholders, and laser welding machines. It will show up in the price of goods sold by professional sports teams, including tickets and memorabilia. Even as supply chain issues plague the country, the GRT will be added to the cost of shipping companies importing or exporting goods through the Port of Boston.

Other likely candidates for Massachusetts’ GRT include the medical equipment producers, pharmaceutical companies, and technology firms that are so prevalent in the Bay State. These companies produce medical devices like pacemakers, stents, orthopedic shoe insoles, and blood pressure cuffs.

The unique function, high demand, and relatively high barriers to market entry in the aforementioned industries can result in firms accruing high annual receipt totals. Less visible, however, are the similarly high input costs required for production: wages for highly skilled labor, research and development costs, emerging technology costs, etc. With high operating costs, it does not take long before a large amount of gross income is reduced to a small amount of net income. For young businesses dealing with startup debt in these industries, mature businesses recovering from an unprofitable year, or narrow-margin businesses that end up bearing part of the tax, the GRT makes returning to or sustaining profitability even harder.

Still other reasons exist to doubt the promises of the GRT—particularly in Massachusetts. At the top of the list is the availability of substitutes. A producer or consumer can avoid the burden of a tax if he can find a suitable substitute that does not impose the same tax effects, but that is not always possible. In those cases, substituting a state may be just as effective. Massachusetts is a geographically small state. Thus, it may be more cost effective to produce or consume through a neighboring state. Consider Massachusetts’ largely ineffective ban on menthol cigarettes. Instead of quitting the habit, many Bay Staters now simply purchase their tobacco across state lines. If the proposed GRT becomes law, businesses that cannot fully shift the tax to consumers may be convinced to move their operations to one of Massachusetts’ more tax competitive neighbors.

Given Massachusetts’ $5 billion surplus in fiscal year 2021 and its sustained revenue levels in FY 2022, it is hard to justify the economic risk to the Commonwealth from enacting a GRT. Not only is the tax inequitable and inefficient, it also could be what drives businesses and remote workers into another state. Consumers who are unable to move will end up bearing the burden of higher prices. The GRT may be remitted by corporations, but tax pyramiding ensures individuals bear the burden whether they like it or not.

Articles You May Like

High inflation harms older households — and two factors determine who is most at risk, research finds
Goldman Sachs and American Express are among the leading companies for working parents in 2024, new study shows
Fewer homeowners are remodeling, but demand is still ‘solid’
Beer giant AB InBev beats profit estimates, with Bud Light boycott set to ease one year on
Refinancing student debt is risky amid Biden forgiveness push. Borrowers ‘forever lose access’ to safety nets, advocates say